Are the SEP Holders prima facie dominant, leading to a per se assumption of abuse under the competition law
A 'Standard' can be understood to be uniform or common technical design
specifications which allow a certain level of compatibility across products or
process. A common set of standards allow an easy interaction among the products.
In various industries such as communication, technology, certain standards with
regard to the design and the specifications are set by a Standard Setting
Organisation (hereinafter referred as 'SSO') in order to have compatibility with
other products and networks (here).
An example of such compatibility would be
the charger of a mobile phone compatible across different sets or a Wi-Fi and 4G
cell phone standards. More often than not, the standards set by the SSO rely on
the patent protected technologies (here). In the case of Microsoft Corp. vs.
Motorola Mobility Inc. (here) the United States court explained Standard
Essential Patent (hereinafter referred as 'SEP') as, a patent which is essential
to the standard and the use of the standard would amount to the infringement of
the patent. In other words, a SEP is the patented product or technology which is
required to comply with the standards set by the SSO.
The industries or the
implementers of the standard would have to either infringe or license the
patented technologies in order to comply with the standards set by the SSO
(here). Generally, it is understood that, the SEP holder gains a significant
bargaining power once the patented product has been set as a 'standard' in an
industry. It creates a beneficial network effect in the market and with the
growth of the network, the market power of the SEP holder grows (here). In
order to ensure that there isn't any abuse of the dominant position gained by
the SEP holder, the SSOs have certain rules in place.
The SEP holders are
required to license the SEPs to the industries or the implementers of the
standards based on fair, reasonable and non-discriminatory (FRAND) conditions
(here). The conditions primarily refer to the royalty paid by the Implementers
to the SEP holders. The royalty is supposed to be comparable to the royalty paid
by the other implementers of the standard (here).
Does SEPs necessarily grant monopoly or dominant position to the holder?
In the case of SEP, for instance specifically in the telecommunications sector,
the sector is known for innovation and the entry of new firms with disruptive
technologies. The sector sees a presence of threatening competitive constraints
which makes it difficult for one player to remain dominant throughout. In an
industry, when there is a presence of competitive constraints it restricts the
SEP holders to charge an unreasonable or exorbitant amount of royalty fees.
In
analyzing the dominance of a SEP holder in an industry from the standpoint of
competitive constraints rather than market power, it paves the way for effect
based analysis in the antitrust laws (here). Moreover, SEP plays an important
role in promoting competition in an industry. SSO enables to fix a uniform
standard facilitating easier negotiations for an implementer to enter into a
license agreement to use the patented product. The understanding that SEPs act
as an entry barriers stands on shallow grounds. The patent holders form a
package in order to seek approval from various SSOs.
The SEP holders choose
among the SSOs on the basis of credibility. The selection of SEPs goes through a
process of seeking approval of the SSOs by way of a package among the patent
holders. It is warranted that, SSOs conduct a forum, discussing the selection
criteria of the SEPs in order to promoter transparency and clarity in the
process. The SEP holders are required to follow the fair, reasonable and
non-discriminatory (FRAND) conditions while entering into a license agreement
with the implementers. Such conditions have helped in the growth of the
telecommunication sector.
The growing market in the telecommunication sector is
a living example of the benefits and the success of the FRAND conditions. In the
antitrust laws, when a dominant player exerts its market power, it is imperative
to consider the choice available for the selection of the product. Specifically,
in the telecommunication market, the FRAND license is voluntary and it is not an
obligation on the part of the implementers to select a specific SEP over other
SEPs (here).
Does dominance lead to abuse in terms of royalty payments?
The SEP holders are required to comply with the fair, reasonable and
non-discriminatory (FRAND) conditions while entering into a license agreement
with the implementers. What amounts to 'fair and reasonable' is often a grey
area. 'Fair and reasonable', as part of the FRAND conditions is generally
understood to be a uniform royalty for all the implementers of the specific SEP.
It has to be noted that, the licensing agreement between the SEP holders and the
implementers are between two unequal parties. Any price which is negotiated as
part of the licensing agreement between the unequal parties is bound to be far
from 'fair and reasonable'. The SEP holder is at a dominant position with higher
bargaining power which makes the licensing agreement anything but, fair.
However, along with the understanding that the SEP holder can be considered to
be at a dominant position as a patent holder, it has to be considered that the
implementers are more often than not, large manufacturing companies which are
not exactly small.
In a situation where the licensing agreement is between an
international SEP holder and a large domestic telecommunication company, it
gives rise to a competing dominance. In such a licensing agreement, rather than
an outright presumption of dominant position and thereby abuse of dominance, the
questions which need to be asked are whether the SEP holder needs the
implementer more than the implementer needs the SEP holder or vice versa (here).
Rather than the presence of unequal bargaining power, the situation hints
towards a presence of competing dominance which eventually helps to strike a
balance in the bargaining power between both the parties of the licensing
agreement of a SEP. The SEP holders are interested in licensing their patents
which will eventually generate funds to cover their research and development
cost facilitating innovation. In light of the competing dominance, ruling out
the notion that SEP holders are prima facie dominant thereby akin to cause abuse
of dominance, uniform royalty rates applicable to all the implementers does not
sound to be a valid argument.
Additionally, the royalty payment to the SEP
holders reflects the value of the patent to the implementer. Each and every
implementer has different products with varied specifications which influences
the choice of SEP. The value of the SEP is product specific, determined on the
basis of the features of the product which the implementers incorporate.
The
value of the royalty is also determined by the consumer satisfaction and the
marginal utility of the implementer's product which is bound to vary from
product to product given the fact that, each and every product is different.
Considering the nuanced factors which affect the value of a SEP to the
implementer, it is imperative to acknowledge the complexities in the licensing
agreements and the royalty payments.
All the cases pertaining to SEPs have been considered under the frame work of
Section 4, Abuse of Dominance under the Competition Act, 2002 in terms of its
anti competitive effects (here). The presumption is that, SEP holders are
dominant and therefore, immune to competitive constraints.
In the case of Micromax (here), the argument has been that, higher royalty
payments results in higher costs to the consumers. In this argument, it is
implied that the royalty rates affect the final price of the product thereby,
costing the consumers more. However, it has been ignored that, in a
telecommunication market for instance, the final price of the product is not
simply based on the royalty payments of the SEPs but, there are several factors
to the pricing of a product.
The implementers decide on the final price of the product based on the factors
of elasticity of demand, the number of firms in the market, available
substitutability among others. Moreover, a change in the royalty payment or a
higher royalty payment in the market will have similar impact on all the
implementers in the telecommunication market (here).
The factors of abuse of dominance are provided under Section 19(4) of the
Competition Act. The approach under the antitrust law is out of place with
regard to the SEP specifically, for instance, in the telecommunication sector
given the fact that, the implementers or the manufacturers enjoy a limited and
temporary position of dominance in the market.
The market changes rapidly and the dominant positions of the players keep of
changing over the time. Additionally, there are number of SEPs and SSOs enabling
a range of choice on the part of the implementers. As it has been highlighted,
competitive constraints are a more plausible way to look at the market which
infers that, an effect based approach under the antitrust law should be a way
forward. Such an approach would enable in indentifying the competitive
constraints by way of investigations in order to determine the abuse of
dominance.
Law Article in India
You May Like
Please Drop Your Comments